The
mentality encouraged by capitalism is to strive for profits at the
expense of long-term consequences. The warnings raised by the
environmentalists and scientists are muffled by the demands of
economic exploitation. We all think it’s bad for ecosystems to be
decimated, for wildlife to become extinct and for the planet’s
lungs to be chipped away. In socialism, with democratic control of
resources and production solely for need people would be able to do
something about it. Capitalist businesses need
to keep costs low in order to maximise their profits, and so the
costs of alternative sources of energy plus their threat to existing
energy interests makes them less attractive, for the capitalists at
least. Of
course, protecting the environment isn’t our only consideration.
The needs of people have to be met. But in socialism, it would be
more straightforward to balance the needs of people with conserving
the environment than it is in capitalism. Once the profit motive no
longer operates, different sources of power can be judged not on
their financial cost and the likelihood of a profitable return.
Instead, they can be judged on their real merits; the pollutants they
release, whether the fuel is plentiful or not, and whether its
extraction damages the environment. In socialism, people would have
more control over their lives and this will include the vital work of
energy production. This would be reflected in the community, and
there might be trends towards communities having more autonomy, in
some respects. And so in some places, power production might become
more localised. A town might have its own wind generators, for
example, and it could still be connected to a “national” grid to
transfer power in if there was a local shortage or out when there was
a surplus.
The
inequalities which capitalism creates everywhere have been brought
vividly to life. Any news bulletin shows us images of starving
children in Africa, and obese children in America. More and more
people in developed countries are suffering from obesity, while
globally, one in five of the population suffers from serious hunger.
But even in developing countries, enough food is being produced.
However, the food which is being produced in developing countries
doesn’t always go to feed the people living there. Instead, it is
being exported. Most of the world’s capital is to be found in North
America, Europe and Japan, so that’s where the food goes. Food and
other commodities follow capital like seagulls follow a fishing-boat.
After a socialist revolution, capital would become obsolete. So, the
reason behind the problems with food distribution would no longer
operate. Instead, the problem would become a short-term, practical
one. Workers in Africa would probably be reluctant to continue
exporting the vast majority of their produce. Instead, they might
want it to be distributed more locally, to areas which might still be
at risk of shortages.
But
this wouldn’t necessarily cause shortages for people in the areas
which are now called the developed countries. Many of them would have
a background of working for organisations which would have no place
in socialism: banks, insurance companies, loan companies. These
people would need to find new ways to spend their time. And food
production is both an essential and fulfilling occupation.
Business
parks and office blocks could be bulldozed to make way for
plantations and food factories. People in Europe and North America
could start to produce more food for themselves, and the areas of the
southern hemisphere which currently produce food for export could
keep more of their produce for themselves. Globally, food production
might became more localised, while still allowing for products to be
exported if they couldn’t be grown elsewhere. In socialism there
would no longer be any need for a community to import wheat from
thousands of miles away when it can be grown nearby.
In
capitalism, natural resources such as land, as well as means of
production are used for the production of commodities which are sold
on for profit to the consumer through the markets. This means that
the potential of resources to be used for enjoyment and the
satisfaction of needs is subordinate to the profit interests of their
owners. If the production of something is profitable, then it
continues, and if it is unprofitable, it stops. The profitability of
a product is linked to the cost of its being produced, and the extent
to which it can be sold. In order to maximise profits, companies
produce as cheaply as possible. This means that corners are cut and
the methods and techniques used are those which bring in short-term
gains rather than long-term sustainability. Labour and resources in
developing countries are exploited to the hilt because they are
cheaper. This is why children in Cambodia and Indonesia are stitching
shirts like slaves, and why cheap forest land in South America and
Africa is being decimated. In order for production to be of minimum
cost to the company, it often ends up as being of maximum cost to the
environment, and humanity. This doesn’t mean that all cost-saving
techniques are necessarily more harmful than the techniques they
replace, but simply that their effect on people or the environment
isn’t the main consideration in adopting them. And if a company
adopts a method of production which is environmentally safe, for
example, but expensive in terms of labour or materials, it will
become uncompetitive. A rival organisation producing a similar
product cheaper will have the advantage, no matter what the
ecological or human cost.
Eventually,
capitalist organisations have to take notice of the state of the
environment, but it is usually a case of too little, too late. They
only take notice once the damage has been done - once a resource has
become scarce, once a reserve of needed water has become polluted.
And if the environmental cost doesn’t raise production costs, then
it is often ignored.
After a socialist revolution, when common ownership of resources and production processes replaces private ownership, when the profit motive has become irrelevant, the factors to consider in production will change. When it comes to our use of natural resources, we could consider how much of the resource would be needed, whether it is scarce or abundant, whether that resource replaces itself over time or is in fixed supply, whether its extraction upsets the ecosystem, whether its production or use releases pollutants, whether the resulting product is durable or not, whether or not it is bio-degradable. All these are considerations in capitalist production, but now they are subordinate to the need to minimise financial costs and maximise profits.
When
land, resources and factories are owned communally and controlled
democratically, there will be no them-and-us. There will no longer be
a privileged elite who own the means of production, so there will be
no-one to sell our time and energy to, no-one who would live off our
labour and pay us peanuts in return. And if and when this change in
ownership happens, the existence of money will become an anachronism.
There will no longer be any need to buy goods from someone else or
sell them to someone else, because you would have as much of a claim
of ownership on them as they would. This would mean that we could
just take what we need from the distribution centres. While
the means of production are owned by a minority, the motivation for
production is to make a profit for that minority. Satisfying the
needs and wants of humanity and protecting the environment is
incidental to this, so no wonder many people are left without enough
food and other goods, and no wonder resources are scarce or polluted.
No comments:
Post a Comment