In 1919, the percentage shares of total income received by
the top 1 percent and the top 5% stood, respectively, at 12.2 percent and 24.3
percent; in 1923 the shares had risen to 13.1 percent and 27.1 percent and by
1929 to 18.9 and 33.5 percent. According to the Brookings Institution, in 1929
“0.1 percent of the families at the top received practically as much as 42
percent of families at the bottom of the scale.”
By 1929, 71 percent of American families earned incomes of
under $2,500 a year, the level that the Bureau of Labor Statistics considered
minimal to maintain an adequate standard of living for a family of four. 60
percent earned less than $2,000.00 per year, the amount determined by the
Bureau of Labor Statistics “sufficient to supply only basic necessities.” 50
percent had less than $1700.00 and more than 20 percent had less than
$1,000.00.
During the steep recession in the first years of the decade
unemployment (among non-farm workers) hit 19.5 percent in 1921 and 11.4 percent
in 1922. In 1924 it rose from 4.1 to 8.3 percent, fell to 2.9 percent in 1926
and was back up to 6.9 percent in 1928. 1922-1926 was the period of fastest
growth in production and profits before over-investment and under-consumption
slowed the rate of GDP and sales growth. Yet two of those boom years saw
unemployment comparable to or exceeding 2015’s official unemployment figures.
Real poverty can be disguised, and the principal means of
obscuring material insecurity when there has appeared to exist a middle class
has been the extension of credit to vast numbers of working households. During
both the 1920s and the Golden Age households accumulated mounting debt in order
to achieve the “middle class standard of living.” Workers’ wages needed a
substantial supplement of financial speed to goose the buying power required
for middle class pleasures. The Twenties were the first instance of what was to
become an abiding feature of American capitalism, the need for large scale
credit financing to sustain levels of consumption required to stave off
macroeconomic retardation and persistent economic insecurity. The Hoover
Commission Report, a massive study of the economy of the 1920s conducted by a
large team of the country’s most prominent economists, reported that:
“The most spectacular and the most novel development in the
field of credit was the growth after 1920 of a variety of forms of consumers’
borrowing… the amount of such credit was tremendously expanded, both absolutely
and relatively, during the past decade.”
The proportion of total retail sales financed by credit
increased from 10 percent in 1910 to 15 percent in 1927 to 50 percent in 1929.
Over 85 percent of furniture, 80 percent of washing machines and 75 percent of
phonographs and radios -indeed most new consumer items- were purchased on time. A prime reason GM
pulled ahead of Ford in car sales was that it enabled credit purchases through
the General Motors Acceptance Corporation (GMAC). Credit was even used to buy
clothes. Young single working women often went into debt to keep up with the
latest styles. By 1929 sales on installment approached $7 billion. Many more
people bought these goods than would have had they had to save the total price
in cash before making the purchases. Credit pervaded the household economy and
disguised low wages, as it would again in the postwar period.
In Middletown, the landmark study of the industrial town
Muncie, Indiana, in the years 1924-1925, Robert and Helen Lynd note the
pervasiveness of credit in the everyday lives of working people there:
“Today Middletown lives by a credit economy that is
available in some form to nearly every family in the community. The rise and
spread of the dollar-down-and-not-so-much-per plan extends credit for virtually
everything – homes, $200 over-stuffed living-room suites, electric washing
machines, automobiles, fur coats, diamond rings – to persons of whom frequently
little is known as to their intention or ability to pay.”
Wages did not increase as rapidly as did debt growth. In
fact, wages remained flat throughout the 1920s. So debt grew to the point at
which it could not be paid. Borrowing and purchasing power then declined in
1926; under-consumption became conspicuous as excess inventories and capacity
built up. Crisis ensued.
In 1946 the ratio of household debt to disposable income
stood at about 24 percent. By 1950 it had risen to 38 percent, by 1955 to 53
percent, by 1960 to 62 percent, and by 1965 to 72 percent. The ratio fluctuated
from 1966 to 1978, but the stagnation of real wages which began in 1973
pressured households further to increase their debt burden in order to maintain
existing living standards, pushing the ratio of debt to disposable income to 77
percent by 1979. And keep in mind that accumulating debt was necessary not
merely to purchase more toys, but to meet rising housing, health care,
education and child care costs. With prohibitive health care costs the leading
cause of personal bankruptcy, debt was necessary for all but the wealthy to
stay out of poverty.
By the mid-1980s, with ‘neo-liberalism’ in full swing and
wages stagnating, the ratio began a steady ascent, from 80 percent in 1985 to
88 percent in 1990 to 95 percent in 1995 to over 100 percent in 2000 to 138
percent in 2007. As debt rose relative to workers’ income, households’ margin
of security against insolvency began to erode. The ratio of personal saving to
disposable income under neoliberalism began a steady decline, falling from 11
percent in 1983 to 2.3 percent in 1999. The debt bubble that became
unmistakable in the 1990s was to be far greater than the bubble of the 1920s;
the financial system by now was capable of far more fraud and treachery than
was possible in the 1920s, thanks largely to deregulation and derivatives.
The majority of Americans were poor. Working Americans were
poor. America was a poor country. In neither period was hard work and the
corresponding wage sufficient to avert relative poverty. In the absence of
organized resistance, the current age of rising inequality, low wages, high un-
and underemployment and increasing economic precariousness will persist
indefinitely.
No comments:
Post a Comment