Each year, Americans spend 37 billion hours waiting in line. By the time you head off to the great queue in the sky,
you’ll have spent an estimated two to three years of your waking life
staring at the back of the person in front of you, waiting to go through
an airport metal detector, use the bathroom, or get past the velvet
rope and into the club.
Nobody likes waiting in line, and nobody
likes it less than economists. Lines, you see, are anti-market, an
affront to the logic of supply and demand. A line is a response to an
underpriced (or un-priced) good. It represents a value system where
time, not money, is the effective currency. In economic terms, those 37
billion hours are a kind of general loss. Huddling in the pre-dawn chill
for a cronut qualifies as neither production nor consumption nor
leisure — it’s just pure economic inefficiency.
Even still, lines have their defenders, like Harvard’s Michael J. Sandel, author of “The
Moral Limits of Markets,” who argues that they tend to do a good job
allotting scarce goods to the people who value them most, the diehards.
“Shakespeare in the Park” is a good example: Tickets to the Public
Theater’s star-studded productions are free, but non-transferrable. You
need to sit in the park all day to go to the show.
Opponents
of this theory, like the economist Ed Dolan, counter that lines aren’t
just a waste of time – they’re corrupt, less fair than the eminently
transparent market. They engender cutting and nepotism and downright
bribery.
Both points have some truth to them. But the line’s
advantage is more basic. Beyond early risers and people with good shoes,
the line has a natural constituency: those whose time isn’t worth much.
If you’re a well-paid lawyer, working long days for a high hourly fee,
two hours in line has a huge opportunity cost. For two hours of work,
you could pay market price and have cash left over for dinner. If you’re
unemployed, on the other hand, sitting in Central Park all day to see
“Twelfth Night” for free might well be worth your while.
In that sense, the line is a very egalitarian concept, demanding the only thing we’re all given in equal measure: time.
It
may also be growing obsolete. Paying to skip has become common, from
Six Flags’ Flash Pass to the TSA’s PreCheck system. Real-time markets,
where price can be instantaneously aligned with demand, have been
implemented to dispel throngs of diners and highway traffic. Where lines
endure, they’re infiltrated by professional “waiters,” standing in for
clients whose time is worth more.
Lines, in all their forms, are being subverted by markets.
The
most well-known example of a real-time market system is Uber’s
surge-pricing algorithm. When cab demand is high (like on New Year’s
Eve, or during a terrorist attack), the price of a ride goes up. This
brings more cars into the streets and shortens the wait time for those
who can afford them. It’s a pretty neat demonstration of supply and
demand at work, an economist’s fantasy realized by the mobile Internet.
It’s
easy to see who wins from surge pricing: drivers, Uber and customers
willing to pay to get some place quickly. Riders willing to share might
also stand to benefit.
It’s harder to see who loses, because the
old way of getting a cab (sans smartphone) was so irritating. In the
biggest cities, where cabs are hailed on the street, demand pricing
displaces a complex hierarchy of street knowledge, aggressive behavior
and luck. But in most places — airports, train stations, cities with
phone-order cab distribution — fixed pricing and a supply shortage
rewarded travelers who had waited the longest.
Lines still
dominate the urban experience. Roller coasters, movie theaters,
airports, restaurants, clubs, government offices, sample sales, traffic:
all these places operate on some kind of first-come, first-served
basis.
But that system is changing. Consumers are doing their
part: The Web has made it easy to hire people to wait on your behalf.
Shoppers can use companies like TaskRabbit to hire “waiters” for Black
Friday sales or iPhone launches. In New York, Robert Samuel became a
media darling for starting what may be the world’s first “wait-in-line”
company, Same Ole Line Dudes (or SOLD). He puts his name down for
pancakes at Clinton Street Baking Company while his clients sleep in; in
the past month, he has also waited for cronuts, passports and early
tickets to the new “Annie” movie.
On
the other side of the line, organizers and planners have long
recognized the efficiency (and financial incentive) of pricing identical
goods or services based on demand. Sometimes, these fees are static —
like peak transit fare, or different menus for lunch and dinner.
More
often, nowadays, they are dynamic, instantly sensitive to interest.
That’s how highway travel works on the Katy Freeway, west of Houston, or
on the express lanes along the Beltway and I-95 south of Washington,
D.C. You’re guaranteed a faster trip — for a price. This is also how
parking prices work in downtown San Francisco, and cities like Seattle
and Cincinnati aim to follow suit.
There’s even surge pricing for beer, at the Exchange Bar and Grill in Manhattan and the Brew Exchange in Austin.
In a way, the mystery is that simple lines persist so widely when the technology to eliminate them has arrived.
The
restaurant industry is a good example. You can make arguments about
fairness for public institutions like the DMV or the highway system. But
why shouldn’t restaurateurs institute a form of surge pricing, charging
a premium for weekend evenings and offering flexible customers a
discount during weekday afternoons?
The
progress of open markets for taxis and tables, though, shouldn’t be
seen as a kind of concession to the plutocracy. The very rich have
always had full-time employees to do the dull work of waiting. They
don’t need Uber; they have drivers. They can hire Thomas Keller to
commandeer their home kitchen for a night.
The
real winners are in the strata below, those who could never have
afforded the premium options, the chartered flights and private
dinners. They could never buy out of the line entirely – but now they
can buy their way to the front.
taken from here
It's hard for many of us to begin to imagine what might be next in line for commodification, but you can bet your life that ideas are being hatched by those looking to benefit financially from something that currently we take for granted.
The 'real winners' are mentioned above but those, the majority, who will never feature in this scenario, the 'real losers', are totally off the radar as they are in all things capitalist. Can't pay, can't play! An egalitarian society, socialism, will have different solutions to scenarios currently requiring long queues or ways of paying one's way to the front and they will be decided by the people, for the people, democratically. Enough said.
2 comments:
"...you can bet your life that ideas are being hatched by those looking to benefit financially from something that currently we take for granted..."
The issue of Net Neutrality quickly comes to mind... ;-j
Yes, indeed.
Post a Comment